Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-6bb9c88b65-bcq64 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-07-26T15:05:26.121Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - Introduction

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 September 2023

Maanik Nath
Affiliation:
Universiteit Utrecht, The Netherlands

Summary

Summary: Rural India has faced a persistent credit problem. High credit prices and harsh borrowing conditions perpetuated underdevelopment in colonial times and continues to affect the livelihoods of millions today. Whereas development economists have approached the rationale behind these lending arrangements in modern times, history of the lender’s strategies and actions in rural India has received little attention. This chapter constructs the framework applied in the rest of the book, drawing from economic theory and situating the puzzle of credit constraints in colonial India against credit and development in regional and global economic history.

Information

Type
Chapter
Information
Capital Shortage
Credit and Indian Economic Development, 1920–1960
, pp. 1 - 13
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023

1 Introduction

The 1957 motion picture Mother India, set in a rural village within newly independent India, follows the struggles of a poverty-stricken protagonist who had borrowed a loan of 500 rupees (about £40 then) from a local village moneylender. The moneylender, with the help of village elites, recovered the loan and additional interest by coercing the borrower to part with three-quarters of her harvested crop, leaving the protagonist in an unbreakable cycle of debt and poverty for the rest of the story.

Stories like these are common in popular depictions of the past. Credit exchange appears as an unequal struggle between the vulnerable borrower and the powerful lender. Money is essential to survival, and so are markets for credit. And yet, the credit market, perhaps more than any other, tends to be seen as a power game and a field of brutal exploitation.

Economic history and development economics attach a different meaning to credit. Credit was not just a source for survival but also a source for modernisation. Unfettered access to credit allowed people to tide over difficult times, consume enough when income dropped, and pay for this service when income returned to normal. Access also enabled individuals to start a business and existing business owners to grow and innovate. How do we reconcile both visions of credit – as an instrument of exploitation and as a symbol of distress against the view of credit as an instrument of economic development?

The book finds reconciliation between both visions through an analysis of rural credit markets in the Madras Presidency, a major province in colonial and early post-colonial India. It analyses historical sources documenting credit markets in the villages and districts of Madras over a period of four decades, investigating variations in the terms attached to credit, and the logic behind the application of these terms. This work tells us that lenders did lend but adjusted the terms to risks and the situation of the borrower. And that geography and enforcement problems shaped these risks and the economic situation of borrowers. In the end, these adjustments created many local variations in types of credit arrangements. Both harsh and lenient arrangements seem to co-exist.

Studying the logic behind lending arrangements explains why harsh terms exist and why lenient terms are not more pervasive. More specifically, the book asks: under what conditions do lenders give borrowers easy access to affordable loans? The history of credit markets in emerging market economies substantiates the importance of this question though is yet to provide a conclusive answer. Problems of selective access and high prices were common in credit markets across the Global South. Moneylenders, notaries and networks of family-run credit businesses commercialised capital markets and increased credit supply in Southeast Asia, Latin America and West Africa at different times in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Loans were often expensive and easier to access for merchants and traders than they were for peasants.Footnote 1 The rationale behind lending arrangements in historical settings – or explaining why loans were supplied in the way they were – remains an underdeveloped field in the comparative history of emerging markets. A similar gap exists in the history of credit markets in South Asia.

Explaining the prices attached to credit in India has fostered an ongoing dual debate, separately among groups of economists and groups of historians. One side of the debate focuses on power imbalance and inequity, indicating that prices were high because poor borrowers did not have enough power to bargain for lower prices and better conditions from the richer moneylenders.Footnote 2 Often ignored in this approach is that policymakers tried addressing power imbalance. Successive regulatory attempts, in the colonial and post-colonial periods, to diminish the market power of moneylenders did not improve the borrower’s position, suggesting that the underlying issue must lie outside of just power. Investigating the rationale behind the actions of lenders, the other side of the debate, the side that is currently filled with scholarship from economists, lays stress on risks and costs incurred by lenders to recover unpaid loans.Footnote 3 Since the 1970s, development economists have tested this approach in field experiments.Footnote 4 History of the lender’s account is overlooked, an omission relevant to readers interested in both Indian history and modern-day development in rural India as types of lending arrangements in colonial times seem to have persisted to the present. Scholars and policymakers have recently cast a spotlight on the harsh lending terms imposed by microfinance institutions, showing that credit still poses the same kind of anxieties as it did a hundred years ago.

The book contributes to a broader discussion on financial inclusion and, thus, speaks to a connected global audience. Providing sufficient credit to poor borrowers is not necessarily an emerging market problem but a central concern in development economics and economic history of the world. Indeed, it is one of those topics in which the two disciplines interact most closely. A reading of both disciplines tells us that the poor had easier access to credit in some regions than others, even though the types of lenders were similar across regions. Banks were not always the major suppliers of credit and even when they were, they seldom catered to borrowers from all income groups and economic sectors. Notaries, intermediaries and cooperatives provided reasonably priced loans to large segments of the market before and alongside the spread of banks in Western Europe.Footnote 5 Indeed, credit from cooperatives facilitated transformative growth processes in parts of Europe as recently as the early twentieth century.Footnote 6 The book visits a part of the world where moneylenders and cooperatives did not supply enough affordable credit to stimulate growth. It finds that a tripartite set of risks, a set that includes region-specific ecology, the design and persistence of colonial institutions, and ineffectual market regulation, stifled lending, especially lending to the poor.

The book, in other words, designs a blueprint to investigate the (under) development of financial markets. In doing so, it contributes to institutional economic history, which foregrounds institutions like law, but has not paid sufficient attention to interactions between credit, debt law and informal arrangements. Familiar institutional typologies divides systems into ‘formal’ and ‘informal’.Footnote 7 Typically, the distinction lies in regulation and scope of the rule of law. Economists and economic historians see independent courts and contract laws (the formal rules) as regulators of banks (the formal players).Footnote 8 Moneylenders are seen in a separate sphere as informal players in markets regulated by social norms.Footnote 9 Recent works on credit in colonial India have started to challenge these typologies, showing that moneylenders used mortgage contracts, and debt laws affected the supply of these mortgage loans in the nineteenth century.Footnote 10 The book shows greater dynamism in the co-existence and flexibility of institutional forms. Moneylenders were indeed affected by laws. They also vacillated between court-enforced and socially enforced contract types, blurring the boundaries between ‘formal’ and ‘informal’ systems. Lessons from this work, therefore, intersect institutional change and policy, showing how the design of laws and types of contract enforcement affected the affordability and inclusivity of non-banking credit.

Colonialism, Credit and Development in South India

The study of agricultural markets is central to understanding economic development in colonial India. Two-thirds of the Indian population relied on cultivation to make a living in 1900, a figure that did not change much until the latter decades of the twentieth century.Footnote 11 Colonial India, as drawn in Figure 1.1, spanned an enormous territory, with long coastlines in the east and west, as well as mountain ranges in the north and south.Footnote 12 Rivers emanating from the mountains run through fertile valleys in the north and, albeit to a smaller extent, in the south. The vast majority of India’s population cultivated on four landforms: coastal plains, dry hinterland, fertile valleys and terraced hills. Colonial Madras was no different. Madras spanned from the southern tip to the Deccan Plateau, which bridged south and central India. Laterally, the province ran from the western to the eastern coastline. Hill ranges ran across central areas in the north and south of the province. Three main rivers flowed from the west to the east, with its main tributaries also culminating downstream in the eastern deltas. The Madras province, geographically speaking, was a microcosm of the Indian sub-continent while its size, covering 48,500 square miles and housing 29 million people in 1950, justifies studies of the region as its own entity.Footnote 13 Agriculture employed millions but yielded low and unequal output in Madras, as it did with the rest of British-ruled India.

Figure 1.1 Provincial boundaries in colonial India, 1909.

Notes: Figure modelled on the map in the Imperial Gazetteer of India Atlas (Oxford, 1909), 20.

Source: Author

Growth and productivity stagnated in the agricultural sector throughout the colonial period and until 1960, in one account, the year when the Green Revolution began.Footnote 14 Agrarian India did experience growth in trade during the nineteenth century. Transport infrastructure improved, markets developed and cultivators shifted from payments in kind to transactions in cash.Footnote 15 Households transitioned from subsistence to cultivation for profit as cash crop acreage saw a steady increase. Despite a process of commercialisation and expansion in commodities traded, real incomes grew modestly and innovation was limited as production processes remained trapped in a low-yield regime. Output was volatile, with some years of mass famine.Footnote 16

Credit supply offered little scope for investment-led growth in colonial and early post-colonial India. Commercial banks did not lend in the agricultural sector before 1960. Private moneylenders and cooperatives were the major suppliers of credit, the former being more predominant during the period. Missing commercial banks did not mean that credit suppliers were scarce. In Madras, moneylenders were present in every village, and each lender commonly provided loans to multiple borrowers. However, access to loans was selective, value of loans was small and prices of loans were often exorbitant. These conditions did not allow the majority of South Indians to invest in new production processes and often failed to provide needy borrowers maintenance in times of famine.

Two types of moneylenders provided credit in rural India. Indigenous bankers and traders from the cities provided credit to some cotton and wheat farmers in select districts within Bombay and Punjab.Footnote 17 In Madras, and across the majority of rural districts in colonial India, farmers with disposable income provided loans to other farmers. Lenders who were also farmers faced two concurrent challenges in bad years. When crops failed, they incurred losses in farming business from decline in quantity, and thus value, of produce, and incurred losses in credit business because borrowers could not meet their credit bills.

The colonial period was a turbulent time for commodity and credit markets in South India. Crop output was volatile, and development was continually interrupted by periods of negative output growth.Footnote 18 Debt defaults, as a result, were common and impossible to predict. Lenders found the precarity in earnings and defaults especially difficult to handle in the inter-war period. Commodity prices crashed during the Great Depression, ballooning the value of unpaid credit bills. Defaults compounded, fresh loans dried up and moneylenders were reluctant to renew old debts. This attracted the attention of policymakers. Soaring interest rates and high default rates in the context of stagnating living standards and rising inequality worried colonial officials and Indian nationalists.Footnote 19

Colonial administrators and nationalists saw credit exchange as an exploitative arrangement. The government acted on a belief that investment remained low and peasants remained poor because market forces allowed moneylenders to extract rents from borrowers. Colonial officials feared peasant uprisings as a result of inequity and power imbalance. Adopting a different tone, nationalists argued that elite-favouring policies in the colonial regime affected the livelihoods of peasants. Key actors accused the colonial government of promoting regressive taxation laws and failing to regulate the power of rich moneylenders. The concerns, though motivated by different factors, encouraged the same policy response. Cutting across colonial and nationalist lines, policymakers promoted the protection of borrowers either as a method of preventing riots in the countryside or as a solution to inequality.

Provincial governments were responsible for regulating rural credit markets. As such, the provinces executed different policy responses at different times from the late nineteenth century. The Bombay Deccan was the first to regulate rural credit markets in 1879. The government in Punjab followed suit in 1900. Both governments regulated mortgage lending to limit the transfers of land from cultivators to urban moneylenders. Urban moneylenders scarcely lent in rural Madras so provincial policymakers did not believe that land alienation needed regulating.Footnote 20 Credit regulation in Madras, therefore, came later.

The government in Madras implemented a two-pronged approach to controlling the market power of moneylenders: one directly curtailing market power by regulating the prices charged by moneylenders and the other an indirect attempt to diminish market power by increasing competition in the market. On the direct approach, provincial officials enforced a price ceiling on loans from moneylenders in 1937. Moneylenders were legally bound to charge borrowers a fixed rate of interest that was significantly lower than the market average. On the indirect approach, the colonial government designed credit cooperatives to compete with moneylenders. The government introduced the first state-regulated cooperative in the Madras Presidency in 1904. The number of cooperatives saw a steady increase in the 1920s with particularly large, government-financed capital injections into the sector in the 1940s and 1950s. The government in early post-colonial Madras persevered with, and even strengthened, colonial-era interventions.

The timing of intervention is central to the book’s structure. The book proceeds in two sections: one analysing the factors that explain lending patterns in the unregulated market and the other showing the impact of interventions on the supply of credit.

The first section analyses the ecological and institutional barriers to lending money and the ways these barriers affected lending patterns in the unregulated market.Footnote 21 Farming was mostly rainfed and dependent on volatile rainfall patterns. Chances of crop failure were high, resulting in dual risks for borrowers and lenders. Poor borrowers that relied on seasonal income ran the risk of defaulting on loans and losing access to credit in subsequent years. Creditors risked losing earnings from capital, returning to more modest means than before. Climatic risk, in turn, affected enforcement structures in a regionally specific pattern. The design of contract laws was unsuited to recover loans from borrowers that did not wilfully default on loans, making courts an inefficient and expensive forum for dispute resolution. The book for the first time shows that lenders in rural India adapted pricing and enforcement strategies to risks and transaction costs. They allocated credit selectively in dry zones and more inclusively in irrigated regions. They relied on courts to recover loans when cost-efficient to do so otherwise resorting to informal contracts, compensating for the costs of enforcing contracts in the prices of loans.

The second section evaluates the design and consequences of credit intervention, showing that regulation was part of the problem of market failure. A political ideology prioritising equity over efficiency inspired the design of credit intervention in the colonial and early post-colonial period.Footnote 22 The book finds that tailoring the market to be fairer to the borrower was a superficial response to the underlying problem. After the government enforced the interest rate ceiling, moneylenders were no longer able to price loans adjusting for the risks of lending. Creditors either stopped lending entirely or evaded the law. Credit supply contracted for the poor and remaining creditors went underground, supplying loans outside formal procedure and pricing loans as high or higher than prices in the unregulated market. Attempts to make the market more competitive did not solve the problem either. Prevailing political objectives led to a cooperative banking structure operating with low savings and weak regulation. The regulatory problem ultimately led to exclusion of poorer peasants from accessing credit and over-leveraged cooperative banks. Regulations to make the market more equitable, paradoxically, left borrowers more vulnerable to credit exclusion and high prices.Footnote 23

The book has an enduring message, carrying lessons for credit and development in modern-day India.Footnote 24 The agricultural sector in South India continues to be fraught with challenges. Poverty levels are high and persistent, inequality levels are rising, and at the centre of these issues are the lack of credit access and harsh conditions attached to credit for low-income borrowers. The institutional setup and market structure changed after 1960. Credit suppliers multiplied with the entry of commercial banks and microfinance institutions in the agricultural sector. Problems of high default rates, selective access and high prices, however, did not disappear. Governments reacted in a similar pattern, acting on a belief that credit markets remained underdeveloped because they were informal and exploitative. Capital Shortage explains how this ideology was founded on a misdiagnosed problem. Risks and ineffective regulations persisted, continually constraining credit supply and restricting investment potential for the rural poor.

Sources

Studying rural credit markets comes with challenges because historical data is scarce. Markets operated within villages, yet contemporary commentators on credit tended to provide broad claims with aggregated data at the provincial level. Government reports and court judgements in colonial India, however, offer novel insights. Policymakers sought to inform policy interventions by compiling data at the district and occasionally village level in official surveys. The number of credit reports compiled by the Madras government increased from the 1920s. That moneylenders often used contracts and approached courts leaves a trail of legal sources that are a valuable addition to official reports.

The book analyses two categories of government reports on credit: annual reports and isolated reports. In the annual category, yearly reports by the government departments responsible for recording land registrations and administration of cooperatives provide data and qualitative information on lending patterns in rural districts. In the isolated category, the first section of the book analyses village-level credit surveys from 1930 and 1935. The Banking Enquiry Committee, under the government’s supervision, hired a team of investigators to survey credit in eighty villages during the late 1920s.Footnote 25 The Report on Agricultural Indebtedness, published in 1935, expands on the data provided by the Banking Enquiry Committee.Footnote 26 The report, through a larger number of investigators, surveyed 141 villages showing data on types of moneylenders, credit instruments used and purposes of borrowing. The second section of the book analyses a series of government-commissioned surveys in the 1940s and 1950s. Two of these surveys, in particular, offer village- and district-level data. One, published in 1946, estimated if credit laws in the late 1930s changed borrowing patterns in select regions. Another, commissioned by the Reserve Bank of India in 1951, surveyed villages across rural India between 1951 and 1954. The book situates data from government surveys against material from other micro-regional reports, including District Gazetteers and one-off official publications on climate and the agricultural sector.

Court records offer a novel set of sources that have yet to be fully studied in credit-related literature. Case files containing counsels’ pleadings are inaccessible to the public. Apart from the laws themselves, the case records that are accessible contain summaries of pleadings and the court’s final judgement. The book analyses case records from the Madras High Court.Footnote 27 The third and fourth chapters examine select case judgements that consider the enforceability of credit contracts as well as the legality and impact of credit policies from the late 1930s and early 1940s.

Finally, the book supplements government reports and court records with material from contemporary studies, written by economists and policymakers directly involved in the committees that compiled government-commissioned surveys on rural credit in the 1930s and 1940s.Footnote 28 These articles and books provide further insights into the government’s approach to rural credit.

The book now turns to the first substantive chapter, providing an overview of agriculture, commerce and governance in South India before and during colonial rule.

Footnotes

1 The edited volume by Austin and Sugihara provides a series of cases studies documenting indigenous microcredit systems between the eighteenth century and early twentieth century. See Gareth Austin and Kaoru Sugihara, Local Suppliers of Credit in the Third World, 1750–1960 (London: Macmillan, 1993). For regional studies of credit in Indonesia, Peru and West Africa, see Gareth Austin, “Factor Markets in Nieboer Conditions: Pre-colonial West Africa, c.1500–c.1900.” Continuity and Change 24, no. 1 (2009): 23–53; David Henley and P. Boomgaard, Credit and Debt in Indonesia, 860–1930: From Peonage to Pawnshop, from Kongsi to Cooperative. A Modern Economic History of Southeast Asia (Leiden: KITLV Press, 2009); Juliette Levy, The Making of a Market: Credit, Henequen, and Notaries in Yucatán, 1850–1900 (University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press, 2012); Luis Felipe Zegarra, “Information Asymmetries and Agricultural Credit: Evidence from the Pre-banking Era in Lima, 1825–1865.” Agricultural Finance Review 79, no. 2 (2019): 217–33.

2 For the economics of debt exploitation, see Amit Bhaduri, “A Study in Agricultural Backwardness under Semi-Feudalism.” The Economic Journal 83, no. 329 (1973): 120–37; Amit Bhaduri, “On the Formation of Usurious Interest Rates in Backward Agriculture.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 1, no. 4 (1977): 341–52. On the history of borrower exploitation in the provinces of colonial India, see Neeladri Bhattacharya, “Lenders and Debtors: Punjab Countryside, 1880–1940.” Studies in History 1, no. 2 (August 1985): 305–42; Sugata Bose, Credit, Markets, and the Agrarian Economy of Colonial India (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994); David A. Washbrook, “The Commercialization of Agriculture in Colonial India: Production, Subsistence and Reproduction in the ‘Dry South’, c. 1870–1930.” Modern Asian Studies 28, no. 1 (1994): 129–64; Neil Charlesworth, Peasants and Imperial Rule: Agriculture and Agrarian Society in the Bombay Presidency, 1850–1935 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985); David Hardiman, Feeding the Baniya: Peasants and Usurers in Western India (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1996).

3 Anthony Bottomley, “Interest Rate Determination in Underdeveloped Rural Areas.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 57, no. 2 (1975): 279–91; Pranab K. Bardhan, “Interlocking Factor Markets and Agrarian Development: A Review of Issues.” Oxford Economic Papers 32, no. 1 (1980): 82–98; Clive Bell, “Chapter 16: Credit Markets and Interlinked Transactions.” In Handbook of Development Economics, edited by T. Paul Schultz and John Strauss, 763–830. Vol. 1 (Amsterdam: Elsevier B.V., 1988); Joseph E. Stiglitz, “Chapter 5: Economic Organization, Information, and Development.” In Handbook of Development Economics, edited by T. Paul Schultz and John Strauss, 93–160. Vol. 1 (Amsterdam: Elsevier B.V., 1988); Timothy Besley, “How Do Market Failures Justify Interventions in Rural Credit Markets?” The World Bank Research Observer 9, no. 1 (1994): 27–47; Parikshit Ghosh and Debraj Ray, “Information and Enforcement in Informal Credit Markets.” Economica 83, no. 329 (2016): 59–90.

4 Subrata Ghatak, “Rural Interest Rates in the Indian Economy.” The Journal of Development Studies 11, no. 3 (1975): 190–201; Pranab K. Bardhan and Ashok Rudra, “Terms and Conditions of Sharecropping Contracts: An Analysis of Village Survey Data in India.” The Journal of Development Studies 16, no. 3 (1980): 287–302; Avishay Braverman and Joseph E. Stiglitz, “Sharecropping and the Interlinking of Agrarian Markets.” The American Economic Review 72, no. 4 (1982): 695–715; Irfan Aleem, “Imperfect Information, Screening, and the Costs of Informal Lending: A Study of a Rural Credit Market in Pakistan.” The World Bank Economic Review 4, no. 3 (1990): 329–49; Timothée Demont, “Microfinance Spillovers: A Model of Competition in Informal Credit Markets with an Application to Indian Villages.” European Economic Review 89 (2016): 21–41.

5 For an overview of non-banking credit systems in pre-industrial France and Netherlands, see Larry Neal and Jeremy Atack, The Origins and Development of Financial Markets and Institutions: From the Seventeenth Century to the Present (Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 2009); Christiaan Van Bochove, Heidi Deneweth, and Jaco Zuijderduijn, “Real Estate and Mortgage Finance in England and the Low Countries, 1300–1800.” Continuity and Change 30, no. 1 (2015): 9–38; Oscar Gelderblom, Joost Jonker, and Clemens Kool, “Direct Finance in the Dutch Golden Age.” The Economic History Review 69, no. 4 (2016): 1178–98; Philip T. Hoffman, Gilles Postel-Vinay, and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, Dark Matter Credit: The Development of Peer-to-Peer Lending and Banking in France (Princeton, NJ: Princeton Economic History of the Western World, 2019).

6 Timothy W. Guinnane, “Cooperatives as Information Machines: German Rural Credit Cooperatives, 1883–1914.” The Journal of Economic History 61, no. 2 (2001): 366–89; Timothy W. Guinnane, “A ‘Friend and Advisor’: External Auditing and Confidence in Germany’s Credit Cooperatives, 1889–1914.” Business History Review 77, no. 2 (2003): 235–64; Christopher L. Colvin, “Banking on a Religious Divide: Accounting for the Success of the Netherlands’ Raiffeisen Cooperatives in the Crisis of the 1920s.” The Journal of Economic History 77, no. 3 (2017): 866–919; Marvin Suesse and Nikolaus Wolf, “Rural Transformation, Inequality, and the Origins of Microfinance.” Journal of Development Economics 143 (2020): 102429.

7 For works on the rule of law and development, see Douglass C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty (London: Profile, 2012). For works on informal norms and trade, see Avner Greif, “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders’ Coalition.” The American Economic Review 83, no. 3 (1993): 525–48; Robert H. Bates, “Social Dilemmas and Rational Individuals: An Assessment of the New Institutionalism.” In The New Institutional Economics and Third World Development, edited by John Harriss, Janet Hunter, and Colin M. Lewis, 27–49 (London: Routledge, 1997).

8 The relationship between courts and banking has a large scholarship. On the design of contract enforcement and its impact on banking operations, see Simeon Djankov, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer, “Courts.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, no. 2 (2003): 453–517; Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer, “The Economic Consequences of Legal Origins.” Journal of Economic Literature 46, no. 2 (2008): 285–332; Andrea Moro, Daniela Maresch, and Annalisa Ferrando, “Creditor Protection, Judicial Enforcement and Credit Access.” The European Journal of Finance 24, no. 3 (2018): 250–81.

9 Sagrario L. Floro and Pan A. Yotopoulos, Informal Credit Markets and the New Institutional Economics: The Case of Philippine Agriculture (Boulder: Westview Press, 1991); Andreas Madestam, “Informal Finance: A Theory of Moneylenders.” Journal of Development Economics 107 (2014): 157–74; Dale W. Adams and Delbert A. Fitchett, Informal Finance in Low-income Countries (New York: Taylor & Francis Group, 1992). On the history of social enforcement and credit, see Gareth Austin and Kaoru Sugihara, “Local Suppliers of Credit in the Third World, 1750–1960: Introduction.” In Local Suppliers of Credit in the Third World, 1750–1960, edited by Gareth Austin and Kaoru Sugihara, 1–25 (London: Macmillan, 1993); Ethan Bueno De Mesquita and Matthew Stephenson, “Legal Institutions and Informal Networks.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 18, no. 1 (2006): 40–67.

10 Rachel E. Kranton and Anand V. Swamy, “The Hazards of Piecemeal Reform: British Civil Courts and the Credit Market in Colonial India.” Journal of Development Economics 58, no. 1 (1999): 1–24; Latika Chaudhary and Anand V. Swamy, “A Policy of Credit Disruption: The Punjab Land Alienation Act of 1900.” Economic History Review 73, no. 1 (2020): 134–58; Latika Chaudhary and Anand V. Swamy, “Protecting the Borrower: An Experiment in Colonial India.” Explorations in Economic History 65, no. C (2017): 36–54; Tirthankar Roy and Anand V. Swamy, Law and the Economy in Colonial India (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2017).

11 Tirthankar Roy, The Economic History of India, 1857–1947 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), 104.

12 India, during the colonial period, included regions governed directly by the British and princely states governed by local rulers in alliance with the British Crown. This book focuses on the Madras province of British-ruled India.

13 Christopher Baker, An Indian Rural Economy 1880–1955: The Tamilnad Countryside (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1984), 3.

14 This view is presented in general accounts on Indian economic history and in national income estimates. For general accounts, see Dietmar Rothermund, An Economic History of India: From Pre-colonial Times to 1991. 2nd ed. (London: Routledge, 1993); B. R. Tomlinson, The Economy of Modern India, 1860–1970 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Roy, Economic History of India. For national income estimates, see A. Heston, “National Income.” In The Cambridge Economic History of India, edited by Dharma Kumar and Meghnad Desai, 376–462 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983); S. Sivasubramonian, National Income of India in the Twentieth Century (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000).

15 John Hurd, “Railways and the Expansion of Markets in India, 1861–1921.” Explorations in Economic History 12, no. 3 (1975): 263–88; Dan Bogart and Latika Chaudhary, “Engines of Growth: The Productivity Advance of Indian Railways, 1874–1912.” The Journal of Economic History 73, no. 2 (2013): 339–70; Dave Donaldson, “Railroads of the Raj: Estimating the Impact of Transportation Infrastructure.” American Economic Review 108, nos. 4–5: 899–934.

16 Tomlinson, The Economy of Modern India, 48, estimates 16 million deaths as a result of famines between 1860 and 1900. Famines in 1876, 1896 and 1899 were prolonged and had a significant impact on most Indian provinces. The famine in 1943 was significant but had the largest impact on the Bengal Presidency. For general works on Indian famines, see Elizabeth Whitcombe, Agrarian Conditions in Northern India (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1972); David Hall-Matthews, Peasants, Famine and the State in Colonial Western India (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2005).

17 The presence of urban lenders in rural parts of Bombay and Punjab declined from the 1870s. The Epilogue provides a more detailed discussion of credit supply in these regions.

18 Heston, “National Income”; Sivasubramonian, National Income of India.

19 Kranton and Swamy, “The Hazards of Piecemeal Reform,” provide a discussion of the policy motivations of colonial and nationalist administrators in the nineteenth century.

20 I. J. Catanach, Rural Credit in Western India, 1875–1930: Rural Credit and the Co-operative Movement in the Bombay Presidency (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1970).

21 The economic history of India tends to discuss geography and political institutions in separate discourses. On geography and economic development, see Tirthankar Roy, “Geography or Politics? Regional Inequality in Colonial India.” European Review of Economic History 18, no. 3 (2014): 324–48; Sunil Amrith, Unruly Waters: How Rains, Rivers, Coasts and Seas Have Shaped Asia’s History (New York: Basic Books, 2018); Tirthankar Roy, “Climate and the Economy in India.” CAGE Working Paper Series, no. 445 (2019). On institutions and state in economic development in India, see David A. Washbrook, “Law, State and Agrarian Society in Colonial India.” Modern Asian Studies 15, no. 3 (1981): 649–721; Abhijit Banerjee and Lakshmi Iyer, “History, Institutions, and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India.” American Economic Review 95, no. 4 (2005): 1190–213; Akhil Gupta, Red Tape: Bureaucracy, Structural Violence, and Poverty in India (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2012).

22 Welfare economics has long contended with Okun’s Law or the trade-off between efficiency and equity. The Law explains the inverse relationship between income growth and equality. Arthur M. Okun, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1975) shows that the ‘leaky bucket’ of redistribution diminishes the efficiency of resource allocation in a given economy. The book applies this trade-off in a different setting, focusing on market allocation and intervention, rather than redistribution. The book shows that the price ceiling (intervention) led to a contraction in supply, despite sustained demand, and a black market for loans at pre-ceiling prices (inefficient and inequitable outcome).

23 The Epilogue suggests that climatic risks and the design of laws constrained capital markets across the major Indian provinces during the nineteenth and twentieth centuries.

24 The Madras province splintered into five South Indian states after colonial rule ended: Tamil Nadu, Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, Kerala and Odisha. When discussing credit markets in the period after division, the book refers to the entire region, drawing on examples from five South Indian states.

25 In the late 1920s, the federal government set up Provincial Banking Enquiry Committees across provinces and published a series of reports on each province in 1930. H. M. Hood chaired the Madras Banking Enquiry Committee. Hood spent the early 1920s as Collector (a term for tax collector during Company rule but evolved to mean Administrator of a district during Crown rule) of the Nellore district. Hood became part of the Legislative Council in the late 1920s and formed a team of policymakers to report on banking in the province. The 1930 report cost 59,000 rupees to compile.

26 W. R. S. Sathyanathan composed the final report. Sathyanathan was a member of the Indian Civil Service and compiled the referenced report. The provincial legislature appointed Sathyanathan as a ‘Special Officer’ to report on rural credit in 1935.

27 There is no accessible resource for case judgements from lower courts. The book finds some judgements from district courts in contemporary accounts.

28 The book makes special use of, and critically evaluates, data and qualitative material presented by five economists cum legislators in the provincial government: C. F. Strickland, P. J. Thomas, B. V. Narayanaswamy Naidu, K. G. Sivaswamy and M. L. Dantwala. Short biographies of these key actors are provided in subsequent chapters.

Figure 0

Figure 1.1 Provincial boundaries in colonial India, 1909.Notes: Figure modelled on the map in the Imperial Gazetteer of India Atlas (Oxford, 1909), 20.

Source: Author

Accessibility standard: Unknown

Accessibility compliance for the HTML of this book is currently unknown and may be updated in the future.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Introduction
  • Maanik Nath, Universiteit Utrecht, The Netherlands
  • Book: Capital Shortage
  • Online publication: 08 September 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009359023.001
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Introduction
  • Maanik Nath, Universiteit Utrecht, The Netherlands
  • Book: Capital Shortage
  • Online publication: 08 September 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009359023.001
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Introduction
  • Maanik Nath, Universiteit Utrecht, The Netherlands
  • Book: Capital Shortage
  • Online publication: 08 September 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009359023.001
Available formats
×